SIGNPOSTS AND CONTRIBUTIONS OF
LEONID KANTOROVICH

Mathematics and Economics—Two Intellectual Stances

Mathematical economics belongs to or at least borders the realm of applied mathematics. The epithets “pure” and “applied” for mathematics have many deficiencies provoking endless discussion and controversy. Nevertheless the corresponding brand names persist and proliferate in scientific usage, signifying some definite cultural phenomena. Scientometricians and ordinary mathematicians, pondering over this matter, usually state that the hallmark of the Russian mathematics as opposed to, say, the American mathematics, is a prevalent trend to unity with intention when possible to emphasize common features and develop a single infrastructure. Any glimpse of a gap or contradistinction between pure and applied mathematics usually brings about the smell of collision, emotion, or at least discomfort to every specialist of a Russian provenance. At the same time the separate existence of the American Mathematical Society and the Society for Industrial and Applied Mathematics is perfectly natural for the States.
It is rarely taken into account that these special features of social life are linked with the stances and activities of particular individuals.
Leonid Vital′evich Kantorovich (1912–1986) will always rank among those Russian scholars who maintained the trend to unity of pure and applied mathematics by an outstanding personal contribution. He is an exception even in this noble company because of his extraordinary traits stemming from a quite rare combination of the generous gifts of a polymath and practical economist.
Describing the exceptional role of Kantorovich in synthesizing the exact and verbal methods of reasoning, I. M. Gelfand, the last of the mathematical giants of the 20th century, wrote in [1]:

Kantorovich's Itinerary

Kantorovich was born in the family of a venereologist at St. Petersburg on January 19, 1912 (January 6, according to the old Russian style). The boy's talent revealed itself very early. In 1926, just at the age of 14, he entered St. Petersburg (then Leningrad) State University (SPSU). Soon he started participating in an interest group circle of G. M. Fikhtengolts (which the Russian name for a students' research group) and in a seminar on descriptive set theory. It is natural that the early academic years formed his first environment that included D. K. Faddeev, I. P. Natanson, S. L. Sobolev, and S. G. Mikhlin whom Kantorovich was friendly during all his life.
After graduation from SPSU in 1930, Kantorovich started teaching, combining it with intensive scientific research. Already in 1932 he became a full professor at the Leningrad Institute of Civil Engineering and an assistant professor at SPSU.
From 1934 Kantorovich was a full professor at his alma mater. His close connection with SPSU and the Leningrad Division of the Steklov Mathematical Institute of the Academy of Sciences lasted until his transition to Novosibirsk on the staff of the Institute of Mathematics of the Siberian Division of the Academy of Sciences of the USSR (now, the Sobolev Institute) at the end of the 1950s.
The letter of Nikolai N. Luzin, written on April 29, 1934, was found in the personal archive of Kantorovich not long ago [2] which demonstrates the attitude of one of the most eminent and influential Russian mathematicians of that time, to the brilliance of the young prodigy. Luzin wrote:
Kantorovich had written practically all of his major mathematical works in his «Leningrad» period. Moreover, in the 1930s he mostly published articles on pure mathematics whereas the 1940s became his season of computational mathematics in which he was soon acknowledged as an established and acclaimed leader.
At the end of the 1930s Kantorovich revealed his outstanding gift of an economist. His booklet Mathematical Methods in the Organization and Planning of Production [3] is a material evidence of the birth of linear programming. The economic works of Kantorovich were hardly visible at the surface of the scientific information flow in the 1940s. However, the problems of economics prevailed in his creative studies. During the Second World War he completed the first version of his book The Best Use of Economic Resources [4] which led to the Nobel Prize awarded to him and Tjalling C. Koopmans in 1975.
The priority of the Kantorovich invention was never questioned. George B. Dantzig wrote in his classical book on linear programming [5,pp. 22-23]:
In 1957 Kantorovich was invited to join the newly founded Siberian Division of the Academy of Sciences of the USSR. He agreed and soon became a corresponding member of the Division of Economics in the first elections to the Siberian Division. Since then his major publications addressed economics, with the exception of the celebrated course of functional analysis[6]-"Kantorovich and Akilov" in the students' jargon.
The 1960s became the decade of his recognition. In 1964 he was elected a full member of the Department of Mathematics of the Academy of Sciences of the USSR, and in 1965 he was awarded the Lenin Prize. In these years he vigorously propounded and maintained his views of interplay between mathematics and economics and exerted great efforts to instill the ideas and methods of modern science into the top economic management of the Soviet Union, which was almost in vain.
At the beginning of the 1970s Kantorovich left Novosibirsk for Moscow where he was still engaged in economic analysis, not ceasing his efforts to influence the everyday economic practice and decision making in the national economy. These years witnessed a considerable mathematical Renaissance of Kantorovich. Although he never resumed proving theorems, his impact on the mathematical life of this country increased sharply due to the sweeping changes in the Moscow academic life on the eve of Gorbi's “perestroika.” Cancer terminated his path in science on April 7, 1986. He was buried at the Novodevichy Cemetery in Moscow.

Kantorovich's Contributions

Kantorovich started his scientific research in rather abstract and sophisticated sections of mathematics such as descriptive set theory, approximation theory, and functional analysis. It should be stressed that at the beginning of the 1930s these areas were most topical, prestigious, and difficult. Kantorovich's fundamental contribution to theoretic mathematics, now indisputable and universally acknowledged, consists in his pioneering works in the above-mentioned areas. Note also that in the “mathematical” years of his career he was primarily famous for his research into the approximate methods of analysis, the ancient euphemism for the computational mathematics of today.
The first works of Kantorovich on computational mathematics were published in 1933. He suggested some approaches to approximate solution of the problem of finding a conformal mapping between domains. These methods used the idea of embedding the original domains into some one-parameter family of domains. Expanding in a parameter, Kantorovich found out new explicit formulas for approximate calculation of conformal mappings between multiply-connected domains.
In 1933 one of Kantorovich's teachers, V. I. Smirnov included these methods in his multivolume treatise A Course of Higher Mathematics which belongs now to the world-class deskbooks.
Kantorovich paid much attention to direct variational methods. He suggested an original method for approximate solution of second order elliptic equations which was based on reduction of the initial problem to minimization of a functional over some functions of one variable. This technique is now called reduction to ordinary differential equations.
The variational method was developed in his subsequent works under the influence of other questions. For instance, his collocation method was suggested in an article about calculations for a beam on an elastic surface.
A few promising ideas were proposed by Kantorovich in the theory of mechanical quadratures which formed a basis for some numerical methods of solution of a general integral equation with a  singularity.
This period of his research into applied mathematics was crowned with a joint book with V. I. Krylov Methods for Approximate Solution of Partial Differential Equations whose further expanded editions appeared under the title Approximate Methods of Higher Analysis [7].
Functional analysis occupies a specific place in the scientific legacy of Kantorovich. He has been listed among the classics of the theoretic sections of this area of research as one of the founders of ordered vector spaces. Also, he contributed much to making functional analysis a natural language of computational mathematics. His article “Functional analysis and applied mathematics” in Russian Mathematical Surveys (1948) made a record in the personal file of Kantorovich as well as in the history of mathematics in this country. Kantorovich wrote in the introduction to this article [8]:
The mathematical ideas of this article remain classical by now: The method of finite-dimensional approximations, estimation of the inverse operator, and, last but not least, the Newton-Kantorovich method are well known to the majority of the persons recently educated in mathematics.
The general theory by Kantorovich for analysis and solution of functional equations bases on variation of "data" (operators and spaces) and provides not only estimates for the rate of convergence but also proofs of the very fact of convergence.
As an instance of incarnation of the idea of unity of functional analysis and computational mathematics Kantorovich suggested at the end of the 1940s that the Mechanics and Mathematics Department of SPSU began to prepare specialists in the area of computational mathematics for the first time in this country. He prolonged this line in Novosibirsk State University where he founded the chair of computational mathematics which delivered graduate courses in functional analysis in the years when Kantorovich hold the chair. I had a privilege of specialization in functional analysis which was offered by the chair of computational mathematics in that unforgettable span of time.
It should be emphasized that Kantorovich tied the progress of linear programming as an area of applied mathematics with the general demand for improving the functional-analytical techniques pertinent to optimization: the theory of topological vector spaces, convex analysis, the theory of extremal problems, etc. Several major sections of functional analysis (in particular, nonlinear functional analysis) underwent drastic changes under the impetus of new applications.

Methodological Integrity

The scientific legacy of Kantorovich is immense. His research in the areas of functional analysis, computational mathematics, optimization, and descriptive set theory has had a dramatic impact on the foundation and progress of these disciplines. Kantorovich deserved his status of one of the father founders of the modern economic-mathematical methods. Linear programming, his most popular and celebrated discovery, has changed the image of economics.
Kantorovich authored more than 300 articles. When we discussed with him the first edition of an annotated bibliography of his publications in the early 1980s, he suggested to combine them in the nine sections:
(1) descriptive function theory and set theory;
(2) constructive function theory;
(3) approximate methods of analysis;
(4) functional analysis;
(5) functional analysis and applied mathematics;
(6) linear programming;
(7) hardware and software;
(8) optimal planning and optimal prices;
(9) the economic problems of a planned economy.
The impressive diversity of these areas of research rests upon not only the traits of Kantorovich but also his methodological views. He always emphasized the innate integrity of his scientific research as well as mutual penetration and synthesis of the methods and techniques he used in solving the most diverse theoretic and applied problems of mathematics and economics. I leave a thorough analysis of the methodology of Kantorovich's contribution a challenge to professional scientometricians. It deserves mentioning right away only that the abstract ideas of Kantorovich in the theory of Dedekind complete vector lattices, now called Kantorovich spaces or K- spaces,1 turn out to be closely connected with the art of linear programming and the approximate methods of analysis.
Kantorovich told me in the fall of 1983 that his main mathematical achievement is the development of K-space theory within functional analysis while remarking that his most useful deed is linear programming. K-space, a beautiful pearl of his scientific legacy, deserves a special discussion.

Invention, Meaning, and Place of K-spaces

Let us look back at the origin of K-space. The first work of Kantorovich in the area of ordered vector spaces appeared in 1935 as a short note in Doklady [9]. Therein he treated the members of a K-space as generalized numbers and propounded the heuristic transfer principle. He wrote:
It is worth noting that his definition of a semiordered linear space contains the axiom of Dedekind completeness which was denoted by I6. Therefore, Kantorovich selected the class of K-spaces, now named after him, in his first article on ordered vector spaces. He applied K-spaces to widening the scope of the fundamental Hahn–Banach Theorem and stated Theorem 3 which is now known as the Hahn–Banach–Kantorovich Theorem. This theorem claims in fact that the heuristic transfer principle is applicable to the classical Dominated Extension Theorem; i.e., we can abstract the Hahn-Banach Theorem on substituting the elements of an arbitrary K-space for reals and replacing linear functionals with operators acting into this space.
To be precise, assume that X is a real vector space, Y is a  Kantorovich space also known as a Dedekind complete vector lattice or a complete Riesz space. Denote by L (X,Y) the space of linear operators from X to Y. In case X is furnished with some Y-seminorm on  X, by L(m)(X,Y) we mean the space of dominated operators from X to Y. Given T:X→ Y and y ∈ Y, put {T ≤ y}:={x ∈ X | Tx ≤ y} and ker(T):={T=0}:=T−1(0).
Consider another real vector space W. It is well known that
(i) (∃ 𝔵) 𝔵A=B ↔ ker(A) ⊂ ker(B);
(ii) Kantorovich's Theorem
Let W be ordered by some positive cone W+ and A(X)−W+=W+ − A(X)=W, i.e., A(X) is coinitial in  W. Then (∃𝔵 ≥ 0) 𝔵A=B ↔{A ≤ 0} ⊂ {B ≤ 0}.
Kantorovich's theorem was the first product of the most important methodological position that is now referred to as Kantorovich's heuristic principle. It is worth noting that his definition of a semiordered linear space contains the axiom of Dedekind completeness which was denoted by I6. Kantorovich demonstrated the role of K-spaces by widening the scope of the Hahn-Banach Theorem. The heuristic principle turned out applicable to this fundamental Dominated Extension Theorem; i.e., we may abstract the Hahn-Banach Theorem on substituting the elements of an arbitrary K-space for reals and replacing linear functionals with operators acting into the space.
K-spaces have provided the natural framework for developing the theory of linear inequalities which was a practically uncharted area of research those days. The concept of inequality is obviously relevant to approximate calculations where we are always interested in various estimates of the accuracy of results. Another challenging source of interest in linear inequalities was the stock of problems of economics. The language of partial comparison is rather natural in dealing with what is reasonable and optimal in human behavior when means and opportunities are scarce. Finally, the concept of linear inequality is inseparable from the key idea of a convex set. Functional analysis implies the existence of nontrivial continuous linear functional over the space under consideration, while the presence of a functional of this type amounts to the existence of nonempty proper open convex subset of the ambient space. Moreover, each convex set is generically the solution set of an appropriate system of simultaneous linear inequalities.
Attempts at formalizing Kantorovich's heuristic principle started in the middle of the twentieth century at the initial stages of K-space theory and yielded the so-called identity preservation theorems. They assert that if some algebraic proposition with finitely many function variables is satisfied by the assignment of all real values then it remains valid after replacement of reals with members of an  arbitrary K-space.
The diversity of Kantorovich's contributions implements the methodological integrity of his contributions. It is no wonder so that he tried to apply semiordered spaces to numerical methods in his earliest papers. In the note of 1936 [10] he described the background for his approach as follows:
There is no denying that the classical method of majorants which stems from the works of A. Cauchy acquires its natural and final form within K-space theory.
Inspired by some applied problems, Kantorovich propounded the idea of a lattice-normed space or BK-space and introduced a special decomposability axiom for the lattice norm of a BK-space. This axiom looked bizarre and was often omitted in the subsequent publications of other authors as definitely immaterial. The principal importance of this axiom was revealed only within Boolean valued analysis in the 1980s. As typical of Kantorovich, the motivation of BK-space, now called Banach–Kantorovich space, was deeply rooted in abstractions as well as in applications. The general domination method of Kantorovich was substantially developed by himself and his students and followers and occupies a noble place in the theoretic toolkit of computational mathematics.
The above heuristic principle was corroborated many times in the works of Kantorovich and his students and followers. Attempts at formalizing the heuristic ideas by Kantorovich started at the initial stages of K-space theory and yielded the so-called identity preservation theorems. They assert that if some algebraic proposition with finitely many function variables is satisfied by the assignment of all real values then it remains valid after replacement of reals with members of an  arbitrary K-space.
Unfortunately, no satisfactory explanation was suggested for the internal mechanism behind the phenomenon of identity preservation. Rather obscure remained the limits on the heuristic transfer principle. The same applies to the general reasons for similarity and parallelism between the reals and their analogs in K-space which reveal themselves every now and then. The omnipotence and omnipresence of Kantorovich's transfer principle found its full explanation only within Boolean valued analysis in the 1970s.
Boolean valued analysis (the term was minted by G. Takeuti) is a branch of functional analysis which uses a special set-theoretic models with truth-values in an arbitrary Boolean algebra. Since recently this term has been treated in a broader sense of nonstandard analysis, implying the tricks and tools that stem from comparison between the implementations of a mathematical concept or construct in two distinct Boolean valued models.
Note that the invention of Boolean valued analysis was not connected with the theory of vector lattices. The appropriate language and technique had already been available within mathematical logic by 1960. Nevertheless, the main idea was still absent for rapid progress in model theory and its applications. This idea emerged when P. J. Cohen demonstrated in 1960 that the classical continuum hypothesis is undecidable in a rigorous mathematical sense. It was the Cohen forcing whose comprehension led to the invention of Boolean valued models of set theory which is attributed to the efforts by D. Scott, R. Solovay, and P. Vopenka.
The Boolean valued status of the notion of Kantorovich space was first demonstrated by Gordon's Theorem [11] communicated by Kantorovich and dated from the mid 1970s. This fact can be reformulated as follows: A universally complete K-space serves as interpretation of the reals in a suitable Boolean valued model. (Parenthetically speaking, every Archimedean vector lattice admits universal completion.) Furthermore, each theorem of ZFC, i.e., Zermelo–Fraenfkel Set Theory with Choice, about reals has a full analog for the corresponding K-space. Translation of one theorem into the other is fulfilled by some precisely-defined Escher-type procedures: ascent, descent, canonical embedding, etc., i.e., by algorithm, as a matter of fact. Thus, Kantorovich's motto: “The elements of a K-space are generalized numbers” acquires a rigorous mathematical formulation within Boolean valued analysis. On the other hand, the heuristic transfer principle finished its auxiliary role of a guiding nature in many studies of the pre-Boolean-valued K-space theory and becomes a powerful and precise method of research within Boolean valued analysis.
Further progress of Boolean valued analysis revealed that this translation (transfer or interpretation) making new theorems from available facts is possible not only for K-spaces but also for practically all objects related to them such various spaces and classes of linear and nonlinear operators, operator algebras, etc. Miraculously, it is the “bizarre” decomposability axiom of Kantorovich which guarantees these opportunities.

Impact on Economics and Linear Programming

It was in the 1930s that Kantorovich became engrossed in the practical problems of decision making. Inspired by the ideas of functional analysis and order, Kantorovich. attacked these problems in the spirit of searching for an optimal solution. Kantorovich was among the first scientists who formulated optimality conditions for rather general extremal problems. Classical remains his approach to the theory of optimal transport whose center is occupied by the Monge-Kantorovich problem. Another particularity of the extremal problems stemming from praxis consists in the presence of numerous conflicting ends and interests which are to be harmonized. In fact, we encounter the instances of multicriteria optimization whose characteristic feature is a vector-valued target. Seeking for an optimal solution in these circumstances, we must take into account various contradictory preferences which combine into a sole compound aim. Furthermore, it is impossible as a rule to distinguish some particular scalar target and ignore the rest of the targets without distorting the original statement of the problem under study.
The specific difficulties of practical problems and the necessity of reducing them to numerical calculations led Kantorovich to pondering over the nature of the reals. He viewed the members of his K-spaces as generalized numbers, developing the ideas that are now collected around the concept of scalarization. In the most general sense, scalarization is reduction to numbers. Since a number is a measure of quantity; therefore, the idea of scalarization is of importance to mathematics in general. Kantorovich's studies on scalarization were primarily connected with the problems of economics he was interested in from the very first days of his creative path in science.
Kantorovich's Siberian and Moscow periods were tied primarily with economics. Mathematics studies the forms of reasoning. The subject of economics is the circumstances of human behavior. Mathematics is abstract and substantive, and the professional decisions of mathematicians do not interfere with the life routine of individuals. Economics is concrete and declarative, and the practical exercises of economists change the life of individuals substantially. The aim of mathematics consists in impeccable truths and methods for acquiring them. The aim of economics is the well-being of an individual and the way of achieving it. Mathematics never intervenes into the private life of an individual. Economics touches his purse and bag. Immense is the list of striking differences between mathematics and economics.
Mathematical economics is an innovation of the twentieth century. It is then when the understanding appeared that the problems of economics need a completely new mathematical technique.
G. Cantor, the creator of set theory, remarked as far back as in 1883 that "the essence of mathematics lies entirely in its freedom." The freedom of mathematics does not reduce to the absence of exogenous restriction on the objects and methods of research. The freedom of mathematics reveals itself mostly in the new intellectual tools for conquering the ambient universe which are provided by mathematics for liberation of humans by widening the frontiers of their independence. Mathematization of economics is the unavoidable stage of the journey of the mankind into the realm of freedom.
The nineteenth century is marked with the first attempts at applying mathematical methods to economics in the research by A. Cournot, K. Marx, W. Jevons, L. Walras, and his successor in Lausanne University V. Pareto. J. von Neumann and Kantorovich, mathematicians of the first caliber, addressed the economic problems in the twentieth century. The former developed game theory, making it an apparatus for the study of economic behavior. The latter invented linear programming for decision making in the problems of best use of limited resources. These contributions of von Neumann and Kantorovich occupy an exceptional place in science. They demonstrated that modern mathematics opens up broad opportunities for economic analysis of practical problems. Economics has been drifted closer to mathematics. Still remaining a humanitarian science, it mathematizes rapidly, demonstrating high self-criticism and an extraordinary ability of objective thinking.
The principal discovery of Kantorovich at the junction of mathematics and economics is linear programming which is now studied by hundreds of thousands of people throughout the world. The term signifies the colossal area of science which is allotted to linear optimization models. In other words, linear programming is the science of the theoretical and numerical analysis of the problems in which we seek for an optimal (i.e., maximum or minimum) value of some system of indices of a process whose behavior is described by simultaneous linear inequalities. It is worth observing that to an optimal plan of every linear program there corresponds some optimal prices. The interdependence of optimal solutions and optimal prices is the crux of Kantorovich's economic discovery.
Returning to the background ideas of K-space theory in his last mathematical paper [12], Kantorovich wrote just before his death:
Observe that this excerpt of the Kantorovich article draws attention to the close connection of K-spaces with the theory of inequalities and economic topics. It is also worth noting that the ideas of linear programming are immanent to K-space theory in the following rigorous sense: The validity of each of the universally accepted formulations of the duality principle with prices in some algebraic structure necessitates that this structure is a K-space.

Consolidation of Mind

Ideas rule the world. John Maynard Keynes completed this banal statement with a touch of bitter irony. He finished his most acclaimed treatise [13] in a rather aphoristic manner:
Political ideas aim at power, whereas economic ideas aim at freedom from any power. Political economy is inseparable from not only the economic practice but also the practical policy. The political content of economic teachings implies their special location within the world science. Changes in epochs, including their technological achievements and political utilities, lead to the universal proliferation of spread of the emotional attitude to economic theories, which drives economics in the position unbelievable for the other sciences. Alongside noble reasons for that, there is one rather cynical: although the achievements of exact sciences drastically change the life of the mankind, they never touch the common mentality of humans as vividly and sharply as any statement about their purses and limitations of freedom.
Science is "supersensible," implying that its content cannot be wholly revealed without humans. Located in the very center of culture, science reminds of the Tower of Babel, the naive but heroic and grandiose project of the peoples of the Earth. Drive to freedom, innate in humans, lives in the unsatisfiable striving for knowledge. "We must know, we will know"-this centenarian motto of David Hilbert resides comfortably in the treasure-trove of common sense.
Georg Cantor, the creator of set theory, remarked as far back as in 1883 that “the essence of mathematics lies entirely in its freedom.” The freedom of mathematics does not reduce to the absence of exogenic restriction on the objects and methods of research. The freedom of mathematics reveals itself mostly in the new intellectual tools for conquering the ambient universe which are provided by mathematics for liberation of humans by widening the frontiers of their independence. Mathematization of economics is the unavoidable stage of the journey of the mankind into the realm of freedom.
The nineteenth century is marked with the first attempts at applying mathematical methods to economics in the research by Antoine Augustin Cournot, Karl Marx, William Stanley Jevons, Léon Walras, and his successor in Lausanne University Vilfredo Pareto.
John von Neumann and Leonid Kantorovich, mathematicians of the first caliber, addressed the economic problems in the twentieth century. The former developed game theory, making it an apparatus for the study of economic behavior. The latter invented linear programming for decision making in the problems of best use of limited resources. These contributions of von Neumann and Kantorovich occupy an exceptional place in science. They demonstrated that the modern mathematics opens up broad opportunities for economic analysis of practical problems. Economics has been drifted closer to mathematics. Still remaining a humanitarian science, it mathematizes rapidly, demonstrating high self-criticism and an extraordinary ability of objective thinking.
The turn in the mentality of the mankind that was effected by von Neumann and Kantorovich is not always comprehended to full extent. There are principal distinctions between the exact and humanitarian styles of thinking. Humans are prone to reasoning by analogy and using incomplete induction, which invokes the illusion of the universal value of the tricks we are accustomed to. The differences in scientific technologies are not distinguished overtly, which in turn contributes to self-isolation and deterioration of the vast sections of science.
The methodological precipice between economists and mathematics was well described by Alfred Marshall). The founder of the Cambridge school of neoclassicals, “Marshallians,” wrote in his magnum opus [14]:
At the same time, there is no gainsay in ascribing the beauty and power of mathematics to the axiomatic method which consists ideally in deriving new bits and bobs of knowledge from however lengthy chains of formal implications.
The conspicuous discrepancy between economists and mathematicians in mentality has hindered their mutual understanding and cooperation. Many partitions, invisible but ubiquitous, were erected in ratiocination, isolating the economic community from its mathematical counterpart and vice versa.
This status quo with deep roots in history was always a challenge to Kantorovich, contradicting his views of interaction between mathematics and economics. His path in science is well marked with the signposts conveying the slogan: “Mathematicians and Economists of the World, Unite!” His message has been received as witnessed by the curricula and syllabi of every economics department in a major university throughout the world.
Despite the antediluvian opinion that “the mathematical scientist emperor of mainstream economics is without any clothes” [15] for a  practical economist, calculation will supersede prophecy. Economics as a boon companion of mathematics will avoid merging into any esoteric part of the humanities, or politics, or belles-lettres. The new generations of mathematicians will treat the puzzling problems of economics as an inexhaustible source of inspiration and an attractive arena for applying and refining their formal methods.

Kantorovich's Memes

Kantorovich life itinerary is not a series of parades and decorations but a path of the perennial war against inertia, stagnation, ignorance, hatred, and misunderstanding. The epoch of the USSR in Russia was the time of collective triumphs, personal tragedies, bright victories, and grim cannibalism. The main moral loss of the Soviet society was the refusal from universal humanism. The excesses of the collectivist eschatology had never bypassed science. Kantorovich. encountered many abominations in mathematics and economics. Careerism prevailed and flourished, and the main symptoms of careerism was Antisemitism aggravated by intolerance to any form of dissidence. Antisemitism had never vanished in Tsarist Russia, since Russia was never a secular state. Some attempts at secularizing the society were made after the October revolution but soon them annihilated completely. The same fate was doomed to many other Utopian if not ephemeral dreams of Russian intelligentsia. The freedom of conscience and scientific outlook could not opposed Stalinism. All-Union Communist Party (Bolsheviks) had attained the generic traits of a totalitarian sect which did not disappear in the USSR Communist Party after the dethronement of the personality cult. The domestic antisemitism was covertly appraised and even inspired by the party bonzes. Soon it became a rather effective mechanism of building a career in the years of the Jewish exodus from the country.
The negative processes did not bypass Kantorovich. The theses of his coworkers and students were hampered or flunked, some obstacles awaited the publication of his books, his articles were procrastinated and his proposals were dillydallied.
In the times of “victorious and developed Socialism” the abomination often wore the cassocks of the «orthodox pops of Marxism” who tried to disavow Kantorovich's economic ideas as well as their author. Mathematization of economics deprived from the vanish of would-be professionalism all his opponents who could not cope with the challenges of the new realities. The unacceptability of Kantorovich's conception for the top stratum of Soviet economists was due to the total lack of understanding of the role of optimal prices which was characteristic of the profaners of the Marxist theory of labor value. The novelty of Kantorovich's ideas for “anti-Soviet” economists consisted in the fact that prices in his theory are formed during the choice of an optimal plan of production rather than by a market. The market in his theory is a mechanism of experimental determination of the optimal prices of production. Kantorovich was a greater scientist than any enlisted “Marxist.”
The years of Kantorovich's life dim in the past. Yet Kantorovich's path in science, lit with his phenomenal personality and seminal ideas, becomes clearer and brighter helping us to chart new roads between mathematics and economics. Most of them will lead to the turnpike of linear programming Kantorovich was the first to traverse.

References

[1] Gelfand I. M. “Leonid Kantorovich and the Synthesis of Two Cultures.” In: Kantorovich L. V. Selected Works. Part I. Amsterdam, Gordon and Breach, 1996, pp. 7–9.
[2] Reshetnyak Yu. G. and Kutateladze S. S.“A Letter of N. N. Luzin to L. V. Kantorovich,” Vestnik Ross. Acad. Nauk, 72:8 (2002), 740–742.
[3] Kantorovich L. V. Mathematical Methods of Organizing and Planning Production. Leningrad State University (1939) [Russian]; Management Sci.,  6:4 (1960), 366–422 [English].
[4] Kantorovich L. V. The Best Use of Economic Resources. Oxford etc.: Pergamon Press (1965).
[5] Dantzig G. B. Linear Programming and Extensions. Princeton University Press (1963).
[6] Kantorovich L. V. and Akilov G. P. Functional Analysis. Oxford etc., Pergamon Press (1982).
[7] Kantorovich L. V. and Krylov V. I. Approximate Methods of Higher Analysis. New York and Gröningen, Interscience/P. Noordhoff (1958).
[8] Kantorovich L. V. “Functional Analysis and Applied Mathematics,” in Kantorovich L. V. Selected Works. Part II. Amsterdam, Gordon and Breach, 1996, pp. 171–280.
[9] Kantorovich L. V. “Semi-ordered Linear Spaces and Their Application to the Theory of Linear operators,” in Kantorovich L. V. Selected Works. Part I. Amsterdam, Gordon and Breach, 1996, pp. 213–216.
[10] Kantorovich L. V. “On One Class of Functional Equations,” Dokl. Akad. Nauk SSSR, 4:5 (1936), 211–216.
[11] Gordon E. I. “Real Numbers in Boolean-Valued Models of Set Theory, and K-Spaces,” Soviet Math. Doklady, 18 (1977), 1481–1484.
[12] Kantorovich L. V. “Functional Analysis (Basic Ideas),” Siberian Math. J., 28:1 (1987), 1–8.
[13] Keynes J. M. The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. Cham, Palgrave Macmillan (2016).
[14] Marshall A. Principles of Economics. 8th edition, Macmillan and Co., Ltd., 1920. Appendix  C: The Scope and Method of Economics. §1 and § 3.
[15] Davidson P. “Is ‘Mathematical Science’ an Oxymoron When Used to Describe Economics?” J. Post Keynesian Economics, 25: 4 (2003), 527–546.

Footnotes:

1Kantorovich wrote about “my spaces” in his personal notes.


S. Kutateladze

February 16, 2022


File translated from TEX by TTH, version 4.12.
On 17 Feb 2022, 12:28.

English Page Russian Page
© Kutateladze S. S. 2022